"Auctioneer Selling Fish from a Platform to an Excited Crowd." M. Prior. Colored Crayon Lithograph. 1870

Under normal circumstances, most goods and services are produced, bought, and sold through free markets. But in an emergency like a pandemic, markets may not suffice. Imagine, for example, that society suddenly needs to undertake tens or even hundreds of millions of virus tests a week (so that employers can put their employees back to work safely). To whom can we turn to produce the testing equipment? There may be many potential manufacturers, and how can we know who they all are? Even if we know their identities, how do we decide which ones should actually do the producing? How much should each produce? And what price should a producer receive to cover its costs?

If we had the luxury of time, the market might resolve all these questions: prices and quantities would adjust until supply and demand were brought into balance. But getting a new market of this size to equilibrate quickly is unrealistic. Furthermore, markets don’t work well when there are concentrations of power on either the buying or selling side, as there might well be here. Fortunately, mechanism design can be enlisted to help.1

1. Markets

Before getting to mechanism design, let’s review why markets normally work so well. Suppose that there are many buyers and producers for some good. Suppose that buyer i enjoys (gross) benefit bi(xi) from quantity xi. Similarly, each producer j incurs cost cj(yj) to produce yj. Hence, society’s net social benefit is:

\(\sum\limits_{i} b_{i}(x_{i}) - \sum\limits_{j} c_{j}(y_{j}). \tag{1}\)

At a social optimum, (1) is maximized subject to the constraint that supply equals demand:

\(\sum x_{i} = \sum y_{j} . \tag{2}\)

The solution to this constrained maximization is optimal in several senses:

(i) total production \( \sum y_{j}\) and total consumption \(\sum x_{i}\)are optimal;

(ii) yj is optimal for each producer j; and

(iii) xi is optimal for each buyer i.

Achieving all three optimalities may seem complicated, but the market provides a simple solution. If p is the price at which the good can be bought and sold, then each buyer i maximizes

\(b_{i}(x_{i}) - px_{i} \text{ (net benefit)} \tag{3}\)

and the first-order condition for this maximization is 

\( b'_{i}(x_{i}) = p (\text{ }b'\text{ denotes the derivative of } b). \tag{4}\)

Similarly, each producer j maximizes 

\(p y_{j} - c_{j}(y_{j}) \text{ (profit)} \tag{5}\)

with first-order condition

\(p = c'_{j}(y_{j}). \tag{6}\)

But notice that (4) and (6) are also the first-order conditions for the problem of maximizing (1) subject to (2). And so the market outcome attains the social optimum as long as p is chosen so that (2) holds. (Mathematically, p is the Lagrange multiplier for (2).)

But how do we get the right choice of p? In a free market, p falls if supply exceeds demand and rises if demand exceeds supply. Eventually, the equilibrating price is found. But this process takes time. In the meantime, the price may be way too high, in which case, buyers who need tests are being “gouged,” or too low, in which case there may be a serious shortage of tests.

There is an additional problem with the market solution: it relies on producers and buyers being “small” so that they can’t individually affect the price. If some of these agents are big (e.g., if one of the equipment-producers supplies a significant fraction of demand), then the optimizations in (3) and (5) have to be modified and a social optimum no longer obtains. Moreover, by withholding supply, a big producer can distort the price-adjustment procedure and generate an outcome in which the price is too high and market supply is too low relative to the optimum. (A big buyer can do just the opposite.)

2. Mechanism Design to the Rescue2

For both reasons, we now turn to mechanism design.3 For now, let us assume that the government attaches (gross) benefit \(b(\sum y_{j})\) to total production \(\sum y_{j}\). (In the next section we decompose \(b(\sum y_{j})\) into the underlying benefits \(\{b_{i}(y_{j})\}\) of test-equipment users.) 

The government is interested in maximizing the net social benefit

\( b(\sum\limits_{j} y_{j}) - \sum\limits_{j} c_{j}(y_{j})\)

but it doesn't know the cost functions \(\{c_{j}\}\) (and may not even know the full set of potential producers). We solve this difficulty using a variant of the Vickrey–Clarke–Groves mechanism (Vickrey (1960), Clarke (1971), Groves (1973)). Specifically, the government announces a call for test-equipment production and has each potential producer j submit a cost function \(\hat{c}_{j}\). It then computes the production levels \(\{\hat{y}_{j}\}\) that maximize the apparent net social benefit

\( b(\sum\limits_{j} y_{j}) - \sum\limits_{j} \hat{c}_{j}(y_{j}) \tag{7}\)

and has producer k produce \(\hat{y}_{k}\) and gives producer k a payment:

\(\left[b(\sum\limits_{j} \hat{y}_{j}) - \sum\limits_{j \neq k} \hat{c}_{j}(\hat{y}_{j})\right] - \left[b(\sum\limits_{j \neq k} \hat{y}^{*}_{j}) - \sum\limits_{j \neq k} \hat{c}_{j}(\hat{y}^{*}_{j})\right], \tag{8}\)

where the levels \(\{\hat{y}^{*}_{j}\}_{j \neq k}\) maximize \(b(\sum\limits_{j \neq k} y_{j}) - \sum\limits_{j \neq k} \hat{c}_{j}(y_{j})\).

Claim: Given that the government chooses \(\{\hat{y}_{j}\}\) to maximize (7) and pays producer k the amount (8), it is optimal for producer k to report its costs truthfully, i.e., it will take \(\hat{c}_{k} = c_{k}\).

Proof: The second expression in square brackets in (8) doesn't depend on \(\hat{c}_{k}\) and so doesn't affect producer k's maximization. In effect, producer k maximizes

\(  b(\sum\limits_{j} \hat{y}_{j}) - \sum\limits_{j \neq k} \hat{c}_{j}(\hat{y}_{j}) - c_{k}(\hat{y}_{k}). \tag{9}\)

But (9) is just net social benefit with cost functions \(c_{k}\) and \(\{\hat{c}_{j}\}_{j \neq k}\), i.e., producer k's objective is the same as society's. Thus, the optimal choice of \(\hat{c}_{k}\) is indeed \(c_{k}\). Q.E.D.

3. Buyers' Benefits

Let us now decompose \(b(\cdot)\) into \(\sum\limits_{i} b_{i}(\cdot)\).

Because government doesn't know the benefit functions \(\{b_{i}\}\), it will have buyers report \(\{\hat{b}_{i}\}\) (as well as having producers report \(\{\hat{c}_{j}\}\)) and, instead of maximizing (7) it will choose \(\{\hat{x}_{i}\}\) and \(\{\hat{y}_{j}\}\) to maximize 

   \(\sum\limits_{i} \hat{b}_{i}(\hat{x}_{i}) - \sum\limits{j} \hat{c}_{j}(\hat{y}_{j}) \text{ subject to } \sum\limits_{i} \hat{x}_{i} - \sum\limits_{j} \hat{y}_{j} \tag {10}\)

Buyer h then receives \(\hat{x}_{h}\) and pays

\(\left[\sum\limits_{j} \hat{c}_{j}(\hat{y}_{j}) - \sum\limits_{i \neq h} \hat{b}_{i}(\hat{x}_{i})\right] - \left[\sum\limits_{j} \hat{c}_{j}(\hat{y}^{*}_{j}) - \sum\limits_{i \neq h} \hat{b}_{i}(\hat{x}^{*}_{i})\right], \)

where \(\{\hat{x}^{*}_{i}\}\) and \(\{\hat{y}^{*}_{j}\}\) maximize

\(  \sum\limits_{i \neq h} \hat{b}_{i}(x_{i}) - \sum\limits_{j} \hat{c}_{j}(y_{j}). \tag{11}\)

By analogy with producer k's problem in section 2, it is optimal for buyer h in these circumstances to set \(\hat{b}_{h} = b_{h}\).

4. Simple Example

Imagine that there is just a single buyer with benefit function \(b(\cdot)\) and a single producer with cost function \(c(\cdot)\). In that case, the government 

(i) has the buyer report \(\hat{b}(\cdot)\) and the producer report \(\hat{c}(\cdot)\);

(ii) calculates \(z^{*}\) to maximize \(\hat{b}(z) - \hat{c}(z)\);r

(iii) has the producer produce \(z^{*}\) and deliver this to the buyer; and

(iv) pays the producer \(\hat{b}(z^{*})\) and taxes the buyer \(\hat{c}(z^{*})\).

Notice that the buyer's objective function is 

\(b(z) - \hat{c}(z)\)

and the producer's is 

\(\hat{b}(z) - c(z)\)

and so it is optimal for the buyer to report \(\hat{b} = b\) and for the producer to report \(\hat{c} = c\).

As usual in the mechanism design literature, the way to align social and individual goals is to give individual producers and buyers monetary transfers (either positive or negative) that transform their personal objective functions into the social objective function. 

Footnotes

  1. This piece is based on a Santa Fe Institute webinar talk on the Complexity of COVID-19, April 14, 2020.
  2. This section and the next are a bit math-heavy. For a simple explanation, see section 4.
  3. An alternative to markets or mechanism design would be for government to simply order some company or companies to produce all the equipment. But this might be an extraordinarily inefficient outcome if these companies aren't up to the task or if there are other companies who could produce it much more cheaply (which the government is not likely to know in advance). Moreover, how does the government know equipment level is  "right"?

 

Eric Maskin
Harvard University
Santa Fe Institute

References

  1. Clarke, E. 1971. “Multipart Pricing of Public Goods.” Public Choice. 11: 17-33.
  2. Groves, T. 1973. “Incentives in Teams.” Econometrica. 41(4 ): 617-631.
  3. Vickrey, W. 1961. “Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders.” Journal of Finance. 16 (1): 8-37.

 

T-026 (Maskin) PDF

Read more posts in the Transmission series, dedicated to sharing SFI insights on the coronavirus pandemic.

More SFI News